The rapid development of the Internet has accelerated the spread of rumors, posing challenges to social cohesion and stability. To address this, a multi-channel rumor propagation model incorporating individual game behavior and time delay is proposed. It depicts individuals strategically choosing propagation channels in the rumor spread process, capturing real-world intricacies more faithfully. Specifically, the model allowing spreaders to choose between text and video information base channels. Strategy adoption hinges on benefits versus costs, with payoffs dictating strategy and the propagation process determining an individual's state. By theoretical analysis of the model, the propagation threshold and equilibrium points are obtained. Then the stability of the model is further demonstrated based on Routh–Hurwitz judgment and Descartes' Rule of Signs. Numerical simulations are conducted to verify the correctness of the theoretical results and the sensitivity of the model to key parameters. The outcomes reveal that increasing the propagation cost of spreaders can significantly curb the spread of rumors. In contrast to the classical $ISR$ model, rumors spread faster and more widely in the improved multi-channel rumor propagation model in this paper, which is a feature more aligned with real-world scenarios. Finally, the validity and predictive ability of the model are verified by using real rumor propagation data sets, indicating that the improved multi-channel rumor propagation model has good practical application and predictive value.
Yafang Dong, Liang'an Huo, Xiaoxiao Xie, Ming Li. Considering individual game behavior and time delay in the multi-channel rumor propagation model[J]. Communications in Theoretical Physics, 2024, 76(7): 075002. DOI: 10.1088/1572-9494/ad3222
1. Introduction
With the rapid development of the Internet, we have entered the era of universal mobile network interconnection, and the channels of information exchange have also undergone significant changes. On one hand, people no longer just passively obtain information from a single official channel, but can also actively seek information through autonomous internet searches. On the other hand, there are more and more platforms for information dissemination, for example, various social networking software and Internet websites are used by people to express their opinions. By July 2023, the number of people using the Internet had reached 5.19 billion, equivalent to 64.5% of the global population. Of these, the number of active social media users reached 4.88 billion, equivalent to 60.6% of the global population [1]. Nevertheless, due to the inherent anonymity of the internet, the public may not consider the integrity and authenticity of information when posting it. Some individuals may even deliberately propagate rumors or false information for various reasons, which may include personal gain, satisfying their vanity, or achieving certain purposes. There is no doubt that the rampant spread of rumors can harm public safety and social stability [2–6]. To effectively control the spread of rumors in the fast-developing social media era, it is necessary to deeply understand the new features that appear in the rumor propagation dynamics.
In recent years, many studies have done in-depth research on the theory of rumor transmission in social networks from different perspectives based on disease transmission models, incorporating rumor propagation mechanisms [7–11], language environments [12–14], network topology [15–17], external environmental noise [18–22] and multiplex networks[23, 24]. For example, Wang et al consider rumor spreading under the multi-lingual environment, and further establish a new model with cross-transmitted mechanism [25]. Zhang et al think that rumor propagation and behavior spreading are usually closely coupled with each other and the interaction will have great influence on the spreading dynamics, so they propose a novel interacting model of rumor propagation and behavior spreading in multiplex networks [26]. Since there is a diffusion-to-reception process in the propagation of information, the resulting time delay is an important and unavoidable factor that affects the dynamic behavior of a network system, which can induce instability, bifurcation and even chaos behavior [27, 28], and therefore some researchers have included time delay in their models [29, 30]. However, the propagation characteristics of different propagation channels are different. Jia et al proposed an improved susceptible nodes, infected nodes, recovered nodes (SIR) model to further divide the propagation channels of rumors on social networks into point-to-point propagation and group propagation, and analyzed the difference in rumor propagation in the two propagation channels [31]. Dong et al further classified rumor spreading channels into a friendship network propagation channel and a media website propagation channel, and proposed an improved two-layer rumor propagation model to analyze the influence of different propagation channels on the rumor propagation process [32]. Shao et al first proposed a three-layer network model with coupled offline and online social networks, and then proposed an improved SIR model to further model the evolution of dynamic processes occurring in multiple interacting network systems, and found that the model has diverse performance compared to the classical multi-layer model [33].
Based on the aforementioned reviews, the most commonly proposed models are based on epidemiological models. However, a significant limitation of these models lies in their disregard for human subjective initiatives in the transmission process [34]. Therefore, some scholars have tried to use game theory to describe human subjective initiative and add it to the study of rumor propagation theory. Xiao et al proposed a rumor spreading model considering evolutionary game, anti-rumor information and users' psychological factors, which provides a theoretical basis for studying the intrinsic laws in propagation dynamics [35]. Askarizadeh et al proposed an evolutionary game model to analyze the rumor process in social networks, considering the influence of people's decisions on rumor propagation and control [36]. Li et al proposed a tripartite cognitive model of information dissemination based on the symbiosis and antagonism of multiple types of messages and the polymorphism of users' cognitive processes under the influence of multiple messages, and the experiments show that the model not only describes the coexistence/confrontation relationship of multiple messages, but it can also perceive the game situation of multiple messages [37].
Indeed, the flourishing development of science and technology has given people more choices of channels to express their views. However, most of the existing studies pay insufficient attention to individuals' preferences when choosing communication channels. The hypothesis of rationality in economic decision making assumes that individuals are rational and act in a manner that maximizes their economic interests. In the era of self-media, online views, clicks, and followers can yield economic gains for the spreaders, but at the same time running a self-media account incurs some costs. Evidently, the process of choosing propagation channels can be explained by a game-like explanatory framework in which individuals typically choose strategies that optimize their payoffs. Based on the above analysis, this paper proposes an improved rumor propagation game model. The model comprehensively considers the effects of multiple communication channels and human behavioral games on the dynamics of rumor propagation. Next, the propagation threshold of the system is obtained and the stability of the equilibria is proved. Then, the correctness of the theoretical analysis is verified by a numerical simulation. Finally, the validity of the model is verified with a real dataset of Twitter.
This paper is organized as follows. In section 2, we detail an improved rumor propagation game model that includes three propagation channels. In section 3, we discuss the existence of boundary equilibria and internal equilibria, and prove the existence of equilibria. In section 4, some numerical simulations are used to support our theoretical analysis. In section 5, the validity of the model is verified with the real dataset of Twitter. Finally, section 6 discusses the conclusions and future work of this paper.
2. Model formulation
Nowadays, a powerful information repository has been created online, containing many forms of data, knowledge and resources [38, 39]. Individuals can easily obtain rich information and services from the information base and have the opportunity to publish information in it. The anonymity of the network provides opportunities for rumors to spread widely in the information base.
Firstly, specifically, the multiple forms of data in the information base provide diverse ways for rumors to be expressed. Through multimedia forms such as text, pictures and videos, rumors can be presented more vividly and attract more attention. For example, on social media, rumors that can be presented in the form of engaging videos will be more likely to attract users' attention, prompting users to share them and thus accelerating their spread. Secondly, expertise in the information base can make rumors appear more authoritative. Rumors often rely on fictional experts or scientific theories to increase their persuasiveness. Real expertise in the information base may be distorted or misused, making the rumor more deceptive. For example, a rumor may claim to be endorsed by a medical expert, creating greater fear among the public. Finally, the anytime, anywhere nature of service of the information bases allows rumors to spread widely in a short period of time. Users can access the information base at any time through mobile devices such as mobile phones and tablets to quickly access and spread rumors. For example, after a rumor is published in an information base, users can immediately share it through social media, creating a rapid chain of information propagation.
Therefore, as an important propagation channel, information bases have an important role in the rumor propagation process that cannot be ignored. In order to deeply elaborate the new features that information bases give to the rumor propagation process, this paper will develop an improved multi-channel model.
Information bases can be further categorized, based on their content, into text information bases and video information bases. Text information base refers to the information collection consisting of information disseminated in the form of text, pictures and links on various social media platforms, WeChat public accounts, forums, news websites, Twitter, etc. Video information base refers to the collection of information disseminated in the form of videos on various video platforms, such as YouTube and TikTok. Therefore, this study further classifies rumor propagation channels into text information base propagation channel, video information base propagation channel, and individual interaction propagation channel. The individual interaction propagation channel refers to rumors spread through interaction, phone calls, text messages, and word-of-mouth. Delineating rumor propagation channels help to understand the characteristics of rumor propagation in different forms and channels, so as to better cope with the spread rumor propagation.
Drawing from the preceding analysis, the model divides the population into three distinct groups based on their varied responses to rumors. Ignorant: people who have never been exposed to rumors (denoted by $I$). Spreaders: people who know about rumors and propagate them (denoted by $S$). Stifler: people who know about rumors but do not propagate them (denoted by $R$). Rumors in text form are denoted by $W.$ Rumors in video form are denoted by $V.$
A schematic diagram of the rumor propagation channels is shown in figure 1 and the relevant parameters are defined in detail in table 1.
Figure 1. The schematic diagram of rumor propagation process.
Table 1. The meanings of the parameters.
Symbol
Meaning
${\rm{\Lambda }}$
The probability of entry
$\lambda $
The probability of removal
${\beta }_{1}$
The probability of text rumor propagation
${\beta }_{2}$
The probability of contact propagation
${\beta }_{3}$
The probability of video rumor propagation
${m}_{1}$
Impact degree of time delay ${\tau }_{1}$
${m}_{2}$
Impact degree of time delay ${\tau }_{2}$
$\tau $
The length of the information interval
${\alpha }_{1}$
The probability of forgetting or losing interest
$b$
The choice intensity
$\varepsilon $
The individual's sensitivity to information at the current moment
${C}_{w}$
The cost of posting a text rumor
${C}_{v}$
The cost of posting a video rumor
$p$
The imitation intensity
$I$
The density of the ignorant
$S$
The density of the spreader
$R$
The density of the stifler
$W$
Density of rumors in text form
$V$
Density of rumors in video form
${\tau }_{1}$
Time required for an ignorant person to receive a message and decide whether to post it or not
${\tau }_{2}$
Time required by the spreader to create a rumor in video form
$N$
Total number of people
The propagation rules are established as follows:
(1) An ignorant individual $I$ can be exposed to a rumor through three different channels. The first channel is the text information base propagation channel. The probability that an individual receives a rumor through this channel and subsequently propagates the rumor is denoted as ${\beta }_{1}.$ The second channel is the individual interaction propagation channel. The probability that an individual receives and propagates a rumor through this channel is denoted as ${\beta }_{2}.$ The third channel is the video information base propagation channel. The probability that an individual receives and propagates a rumor through this channel is denoted as ${\beta }_{3}.$
(2) A spreader $S$ will propagate rumors through three propagation channels. Posting rumors in text information base, posting rumors in video information base, and interacting with others to propagate rumors. Spreaders $S$ will choose which propagation channel to utilize for maximizing their own benefits by evaluating their potential gains.
(3) The spreader $S$ is transformed into a stifler $R$ by forgetting or losing interest in propagating the rumor with a certain probability ${\alpha }_{1}.$
(4) The ignorant $I$ who receives a message takes time to decide whether to post it or not. This period of time causes a delay in the transformation of the individual's state, denoted by ${\tau }_{1}.$ In addition, the spreader $S$ spends some time in creating the rumor in video form, and the delay caused by this period of time is denoted by ${\tau }_{2}.$
(5) Individuals enter the community at a rate of ${\rm{\Lambda }}$ and move out of the community at a rate of $\lambda .$ Rumors in text form and rumors in video form move out of the information base at a rate of $\lambda .$
According to the hypothesis of rational humans, to maximize their profit, spreaders will consider the benefits and corresponding costs of each strategy when propagating rumors, so as to choose the optimal propagation strategy. This decision making process can be regarded as a game process, in which the spreader needs to choose between propagation and non-propagation to maximize their payoff. This decision making process can be formalized as a game theory model. Specifically, the spreader can be considered as a game participant, and propagation and non-propagation as two alternative strategies for this participant. At the same time, the audience group can be considered as another player whose response can influence the benefits of the spreader. In this model, the expected payoff to a spreader for converting a rumor into text form and posting it to a text information base is denoted by ${g}_{w},$ the benefits (including the attention and reputation received after propagating the rumor) that can be derived from the strategy is denoted by ${Q}_{w}$ and the corresponding costs (including the time cost, the risk of blocking and the risk of reputation damage) are denoted by ${C}_{w}.$ Similarly, the expected payoff to a spreader for converting a rumor into video form and posting it to a text information base is denoted by ${g}_{v},$ the benefits (including the attention and reputation received after propagating the rumor) that can be derived from the strategy are denoted by ${Q}_{v},$ and the corresponding costs (including the time cost, the risk of blocking and the risk of reputation damage) are denoted by ${C}_{v}.$
where ${Q}_{w}(I,W)={{\rm{e}}}^{-{m}_{1}{\tau }_{1}}{\beta }_{1}NIW$ and ${Q}_{v}(I,V)={{\rm{e}}}^{-{m}_{1}{\tau }_{1}}{\beta }_{3}NIV.$ Specifically, when a spreader chooses the strategy of propagating rumors through the text information base channel, the probability that an ignorant come into contact with a rumor in the text information base and successfully transform into a spreader is denoted as ${\beta }_{1}IW.$ Consequently, under this strategy, the total number of individuals transforming from the ignorant to spreaders is represented as ${\beta }_{1}NIW.$ Considering the time delay factor, this transformation quantity is further expressed as ${{\rm{e}}}^{-{m}_{1}{\tau }_{1}}{\beta }_{1}NIW.$ In this paper, we consider this transformation quantity as the benefit of the spreader's choice of this strategy, i.e., the exposure and influence that the spreader gains.
Similarly, when a spreader chooses the strategy of propagating through the video information base channel, the probability that an ignorant come into contact with a rumor in the video information base and successfully transform into spreaders is denoted as ${\beta }_{2}IV.$ Therefore, under this strategy, the total transformation quantity is ${\beta }_{2}NIV.$ Considering the time delay factor, this transformation quantity is further expressed as ${{\rm{e}}}^{-{m}_{1}{\tau }_{1}}{\beta }_{2}NIV.$ This transformation quantity is considered to be the benefit of the spreader's choice of this strategy, i.e., the exposure and influence gained by the spreader. It is more realistic to assume that individuals make decisions by combining payoff at the current moment and payoff in the past period.
where $\tau $ denotes the length of time that an individual considers the payoff when choosing a strategy and $\varepsilon $ reflects the individual's sensitivity to the payoff at the current moment. When $\varepsilon =0,$ it indicates that individuals only consider the payoff of past periods when choosing strategies; when $\tau =0,$ it indicates that individuals are only influenced by the payoff at the current moment when choosing strategies. In addition, an exponentially decaying memory function $K(t)=\alpha {{\rm{e}}}^{-\alpha t}$ is used to characterize the effect of information accumulated over time on spreaders' communication decisions. The decision payoff matrix of spreaders is shown in table 2.
Table 2. The payoff matrix.
Strategy/type
Rumor in the text information base
Rumor in the video information base
Propagate
${M}_{1}$
${M}_{2}$
Non-propagate
0
0
Obviously, whether an individual chooses the information base channel to spread rumors depends on the final payoff function. Therefore, combined with the Fermi function [40], the rate at which an individual changes strategy is assumed to be a nonlinear response function to the final payoff function.
where $b$ is the choice intensity. A larger $b$ indicates that the individual is more sensitive to payoff and more rational, even if the difference between the expected payoff of the two strategies is small [41]. Let $p=a{v}_{0}$ denote the imitation intensity factor, where ${v}_{0}$ represents the rate at which one individual is linked to another or the information base, and $a$ represents the degree of influence. When ${M}_{1}(t)\gt 0,$ i.e., when the final payoff of choosing the text information base dissemination strategy is positive, the spreaders are likely to choose this channel to propagate rumors. And the larger ${M}_{1}(t)$ is, the higher the probability of choosing this channel. When ${M}_{1}(t)\lt 0,$ i.e., when the final payoff of choosing the text information base dissemination strategy is negative, the spreaders will not choose this channel to spread rumors according to the rational man assumption. When ${M}_{1}(t)=0,$ individuals do not change their strategy. Similarly, the decision process of whether a spreader chooses the video information base propagation channel strategy is also divided into these three categories. According to the above analysis, the proportion $x$ of spreaders choosing the text information base propagation channel strategy and the proportion $y$ of spreaders choosing the video information base propagation channel strategy satisfy the differential equation shown below [42].
According to the above rumor propagation rules and the game behavior analysis of the channel selection by the spreader, the following is the mean field equation of the multi-channel rumor propagation model constructed in this paper,
In this section, the system (9) will be analyzed theoretically. Firstly, we use the next generation matrix method to find the basic regeneration number of the system (9). Subsequently, we get the boundary equilibrium point and the internal equilibrium point of the system. Finally, we further analyze the stability of the equilibrium points.
Considering the practical implications of $x,y,$ the system exists in the following three cases. When $x=0$ and $y=0,$ the system (9) always has a rumor-free equilibrium point ${E}_{1}^{0}=\left(\displaystyle \frac{{\rm{\Lambda }}}{\lambda },0,0,0,0,0,0\right).$ When $x=1,y=0,$ the system (9) always has a rumor-free equilibrium point ${E}_{2}^{0}=\left(\displaystyle \frac{{\rm{\Lambda }}}{\lambda },0,0,0,0,1,0\right).$ When $x=0,y=1,$ the system (9) always has a rumor-free equilibrium point ${E}_{3}^{0}=\left(\displaystyle \frac{{\rm{\Lambda }}}{\lambda },0,0,0,0,0,1\right).$ Further using the next generation matrix method, the corresponding basic regeneration number is ${R}_{0}=\displaystyle \frac{{\beta }_{2}{\rm{\Lambda }}}{\lambda \left({\alpha }_{1}+\lambda \right){{\rm{e}}}^{{m}_{1}{\tau }_{1}}}.$ Then, define ${R}_{1}\,=\displaystyle \frac{({\beta }_{1}+{\beta }_{2}\lambda ){\rm{\Lambda }}}{{\lambda }^{2}({\alpha }_{1}+\lambda ){{\rm{e}}}^{{m}_{1}{\tau }_{1}}}$ and ${R}_{2}=\displaystyle \frac{({\beta }_{3}{{\rm{e}}}^{-{m}_{2}{\tau }_{2}}+{\beta }_{2}\lambda ){\rm{\Lambda }}}{{\lambda }^{2}({\alpha }_{1}+\lambda ){{\rm{e}}}^{{m}_{1}{\tau }_{1}}}.$
Next, we analyze the other possible equilibrium points in the system (9) in the three cases mentioned above. When $S\ne 0,$ there exist three corresponding rumor-prevailing equilibrium points.
The above six are the boundary equilibrium points, and the following is to consider whether there is an internal equilibrium point. Let the right end of each equation in system (9) be 0, we can obtain
Then, the internal equilibrium point ${E}_{7}^{* }\,=\,({I}_{7}^{* },{S}_{7}^{* },{R}_{7}^{* },{W}_{7}^{* },{V}_{7}^{* },{x}_{7}^{* },{y}_{7}^{* })$ is obtained, where
It is easy to know that the zero of equation (12) in the range ${S}^{* }\in \left(\left(0,\right.\displaystyle \frac{{\rm{\Lambda }}}{({\alpha }_{1}+\lambda ){{\rm{e}}}^{{m}_{1}{\tau }_{1}}}\right]$ is the rumor-prevailing equilibrium of system (10). Obviously, $G(0)=\displaystyle \frac{({C}_{w}+{C}_{v}){{\rm{e}}}^{{m}_{1}{\tau }_{1}}}{N}.$
From equations (13)–(15), there exists an ${S}^{* }$ in the interval $\left(\left(0,\right.\,\displaystyle \frac{{\rm{\Lambda }}}{({\alpha }_{1}+\lambda ){{\rm{e}}}^{{m}_{1}{\tau }_{1}}}\right]$ when ${R}_{0}\gt 1$ and ${\rm{\Lambda }}\gt \displaystyle \frac{({C}_{w}+{C}_{v}){{\rm{e}}}^{{m}_{1}{\tau }_{1}}}{N}.$ At this point $G({S}^{* })=0.$
Then, we prove the uniqueness of ${S}^{* }.$ From equation (11), we can get ${\beta }_{2}\displaystyle \frac{{\rm{\Lambda }}-({\alpha }_{1}+\lambda ){{\rm{e}}}^{{m}_{1}{\tau }_{1}}{S}^{* }}{\lambda }-{{\rm{e}}}^{{m}_{1}{\tau }_{1}}({\alpha }_{1}+\lambda )\lt 0.$ Then we have
It is easy to obtain that $G$ is strictly decreasing at each of its zeros. If there exists another rumor-prevailing equilibrium point ${S}_{1}^{* }$ excepts ${S}^{* }$ satisfies that ${G}^{\text{'}}({S}_{1}^{* })\geqslant 0,$ which leads to a contradiction.
Then, we analyze the local stability of the above equilibria when $\tau \geqslant 0.$ Let ${E}_{n}=({I}_{n},{S}_{n},{R}_{n},{W}_{n},{V}_{n},{x}_{n},{y}_{n}),$ denote the equilibrium point of the system, and for the sake of analysis, let
Let $\left(I,S,R,W,V,x,y\right)$ $={{\rm{e}}}^{\mu t}\left({h}_{1},{h}_{2},{h}_{3},{h}_{4},{h}_{5},{h}_{6},{h}_{7}\right)$ be an exponential solution of the linearized system, where $\mu $ and $h$ are constants, bring them into the linear system and use $\displaystyle {\int }_{t-\tau }^{t}{h}_{i}{{\rm{e}}}^{-\mu \eta }\alpha {{\rm{e}}}^{-\alpha (t-\eta )}{\rm{d}}\eta =\displaystyle \frac{\alpha (1-{{\rm{e}}}^{-(\mu +\alpha )\tau }){h}_{i}{{\rm{e}}}^{-\mu \eta }}{\mu +\alpha }.$ Then the characteristic equation can be obtained by calculating,
Theorem 2. The stability of the boundary equilibria of the system is as follows:
(1) When ${R}_{0}\lt 1,$ the rumor-free equilibrium point ${E}_{1}^{0}$ is locally asymptotically stable.
(2) The rumor-free equilibrium points ${E}_{2}^{0},$${E}_{3}^{0}$ and ${E}_{4}^{* }$ are always unstable.
(3) When ${C}_{w}\lt \displaystyle \frac{{\beta }_{1}N{\rm{\Lambda }}{{\rm{e}}}^{-{m}_{1}{\tau }_{1}}}{{\beta }_{1}+{\beta }_{2}\lambda }\left(1-\displaystyle \frac{1}{{R}_{1}}\right),$ the rumor-prevailing equilibrium point ${E}_{5}^{* }$ is locally asymptotically stable.
(4) When ${C}_{v}\lt \displaystyle \frac{{\beta }_{3}N{\rm{\Lambda }}{{\rm{e}}}^{-{m}_{1}{\tau }_{1}}}{{\beta }_{3}+{\beta }_{2}\lambda {{\rm{e}}}^{{m}_{2}{\tau }_{2}}}\left(1-\tfrac{1}{{R}_{2}}\right),$${R}_{2}\gt 1,$ and $\lambda {I}_{6}^{* }\lt {\rm{\Lambda }},$ the rumor epidemic equilibrium point ${E}_{6}^{* }$ is locally asymptotically stable.
Proof. (1) Firstly, we analyze the equilibrium point ${E}_{1}^{0}=\left(\displaystyle \frac{{\rm{\Lambda }}}{\lambda },0,0,0,0,0,0\right)$ and bring it into equation (12) to get its corresponding characteristic equation
It is easy to obtain that the above equation has characteristic roots ${\theta }_{1}=-p\left(\displaystyle \frac{1}{1+{{\rm{e}}}^{-b{c}_{w}(1+\varepsilon -{{\rm{e}}}^{-\alpha \tau })}}-\displaystyle \frac{1}{2}\right)\gt 0,$ so the equilibrium point ${E}_{2}^{0}$ is unstable.
(3) For the equilibrium point ${E}_{3}^{0},$ its corresponding characteristic equation is
It is easy to obtain that the above equation has characteristic roots ${\theta }_{1}=-p\left(\displaystyle \frac{1}{1+{{\rm{e}}}^{-b{c}_{v}(1+\varepsilon -{{\rm{e}}}^{-\alpha \tau })}}-\displaystyle \frac{1}{2}\right)\gt 0,$ so the equilibrium point ${E}_{2}^{0}$ is unstable.
(4) For the equilibrium point ${E}_{4}^{* },$ its corresponding characteristic equation is
It is easy to obtain that the above equation has characteristic roots ${\theta }_{1}={\beta }_{2}-2{\lambda }^{2}{{\rm{e}}}^{{m}_{1}{\tau }_{1}}-\displaystyle \frac{{\alpha }_{1}\lambda }{{\alpha }_{1}+\lambda }+\sqrt{{Q}_{10}}\gt 0,$ where
It is easy to obtain that the characteristic roots of the above equation satisfy the following relation, ${\theta }_{1}={\theta }_{2}=-\lambda \lt 0,$${\theta }_{3}=p\left(\displaystyle \frac{1}{1+{e}^{-b{c}_{w}(1+\varepsilon -{{\rm{e}}}^{-\alpha \tau })}}-\displaystyle \frac{1}{2}\right)\lt 0,$ when ${C}_{v}\lt \displaystyle \frac{{\beta }_{3}N{\rm{\Lambda }}{{\rm{e}}}^{-{m}_{1}{\tau }_{1}}}{{\beta }_{3}+{\beta }_{2}\lambda {{\rm{e}}}^{{m}_{2}{\tau }_{2}}}\left(1-\displaystyle \frac{1}{{R}_{3}^{0}}\right),$ we have ${\theta }_{4}=-p\left(\displaystyle \frac{1}{1+{{\rm{e}}}^{-b{P}_{1}(6)}}-\displaystyle \frac{1}{2}\right)\lt 0.$
${\theta }_{5},$${\theta }_{6}$ and ${\theta }_{7}$ satisfy the following equation
When ${R}_{2}\gt 1,$ we have ${a}_{2}\lt 0.$ When $\lambda {I}_{6}^{* }\lt {\rm{\Lambda }},$ we have ${a}_{3}\lt 0.$ According to Descartes' Rule of Sign, the equation ${a}_{1}{\theta }^{3}+{a}_{2}{\theta }^{2}+{a}_{3}\theta +{a}_{4}=0$ has three negative roots and no positive roots if the above conditions are met. Therefore ${E}_{6}^{* }$ is locally asymptotically stable.
Theorem 3. The internal equilibrium point ${E}_{7}^{* }$ of system (9) is unstable.
Proof. The corresponding characteristic equation of the system at the equilibrium point ${E}_{7}^{* }$ is
According to the Routh–Hurwith criterion, Routh table with at least one change of sign in the first column element, the polynomial has at least one right half-plane zero, so the internal equilibrium point ${E}_{7}^{* }$ of the system is unstable. The proof is completed.
4. Numerical simulation
In this section, the correctness of the above theoretical results is verified by numerical simulations, and sensitivity analysis is done for important parameters. The comparison with the classical $ISR$ model is made to confirm the superiority of the $ISRWVxy$ model.
4.1. Stability simulation of equilibria for system
Example 1. Consider one of the scenarios of system (9): ${\rm{\Lambda }}=0.25,$$\lambda =0.25,$${\beta }_{1}=0.4,$${\beta }_{2}=0.35,$${\beta }_{3}=0.55,$${\alpha }_{1}=0.2,$${\tau }_{1}=5,{\tau }_{2}=1,b=0.2,$ $\varepsilon =0.2,{C}_{w}\,=10,{C}_{v}\,=20,p=0.4,$$\alpha =0.2,$$\tau =2,N=1000.$ By calculation, we get ${R}_{0}=\displaystyle \frac{{\beta }_{2}{\rm{\Lambda }}}{\lambda ({\alpha }_{1}+\lambda ){{\rm{e}}}^{{m}_{1}{\tau }_{1}}}\approx 0.22\lt 1.$ From Theorem 1, we know that there exists a unique boundary rumor-free equilibrium point for system (9) when ${R}_{0}\lt 1.$ As shown in figure 2, the proportions $x$ and $y$ of spreaders uploading rumors in text form and rumors in video form tend to 0 as time goes on, and the density of the spreader tends to 0 indicating that the system eventually attains a stable state.
Figure 2. The stability of equilibrium ${E}_{1}^{0}$ of system (9).
Example 2. Consider another scenario of system (9): ${\rm{\Lambda }}=0.2,$$\lambda =0.19,$${\beta }_{1}=0.45,$${\beta }_{2}=0.2,$${\beta }_{3}=0.55,$${\alpha }_{1}=0.15,$${\tau }_{1}=5,{\tau }_{2}=10,b=0.2,$ $\varepsilon =0.2,{C}_{w}=10,{C}_{v}=20,p=0.4,$$\alpha =0.2,$$\tau =10,N=1000.$ In this scenario, the calculation gives ${R}_{1}=\displaystyle \frac{({\beta }_{1}+{\beta }_{2}\lambda ){\rm{\Lambda }}}{{\lambda }^{2}({\alpha }_{1}+\lambda ){{\rm{e}}}^{{m}_{1}{\tau }_{1}}}\approx 3.08\gt 1,$${C}_{v}\lt \displaystyle \frac{{\beta }_{1}N{\rm{\Lambda }}{{\rm{e}}}^{-{m}_{1}{\tau }_{1}}}{{\beta }_{1}+{\beta }_{2}\lambda }\left(1-\displaystyle \frac{1}{{R}_{1}}\right)\approx 48.13,$ which satisfies the condition in Theorem 2 (3), indicating that there is a boundary rumor epidemic equilibrium point in the system (9). As shown in figure 3, with the boundary conditions $x=0$ and $y=1,$ the system eventually reaches a steady state, and the spreader persists in the system and do not die out, indicating that the rumor will always exist in the system.
Figure 3. The stability of equilibrium ${E}_{5}^{* }$ of system (9).
Example 3. Consider the third scenario as, ${\rm{\Lambda }}=0.25,$$\lambda =0.22,$${\beta }_{1}=0.3,$${\beta }_{2}=0.2,\,{\beta }_{3}=0.45,\,{\alpha }_{1}=0.12,$ ${\tau }_{1}=5,{\tau }_{2}=1,b=0.2,$${\tau }_{1}=5,{\tau }_{2}=1,b=0.2,$$\varepsilon =0.2,{C}_{w}=20,{C}_{v}=10,$$p=0.6,$$\alpha =0.2,$$\tau =10,$$N\,=1000.$ In this scenario, the calculation gives ${R}_{2}\,=\displaystyle \frac{\left({\beta }_{3}{{\rm{e}}}^{-{m}_{2}{\tau }_{2}}+{\beta }_{2}\lambda \right){\rm{\Lambda }}}{{\lambda }^{2}({\alpha }_{1}+\lambda ){{\rm{e}}}^{{m}_{1}{\tau }_{1}}}\approx 2.05\gt 1$, ${C}_{v}\lt \displaystyle \frac{{\beta }_{3}N{\rm{\Lambda }}{{\rm{e}}}^{-{m}_{1}{\tau }_{1}}}{{\beta }_{3}+{\beta }_{2}\lambda {{\rm{e}}}^{{m}_{2}{\tau }_{2}}}\left(1-\displaystyle \frac{1}{{R}_{3}^{0}}\right)\approx 37.97,$ and $\lambda {I}_{6}^{* }\approx 0.12\lt {\rm{\Lambda }}$, which satisfies the condition in Theorem 2 (4), indicating that there is a boundary rumor epidemic equilibrium point in the system. As shown in figure 4, with the boundary condition of $x=1,y=0,$ the system eventually reaches the steady state and the spreader persist in the system and do not die out, indicating that the rumor will persist in the system.
Figure 4. The stability of equilibrium ${E}_{6}^{* }$ of system (9).
4.2. Sensitivity analysis
In system (9), it is evident that individual game behavior plays a crucial role in the rumor propagation process. When a spreader decides whether to post a text or video rumor in the information base, their attention is centered on their payoff. Therefore, we will separately simulate the impact of posting cost and time delay on the spreader's channel selection strategy separately.
Figure 5 illustrates the impact of the cost ${C}_{w}$ for posting rumors in text form on the proportion of spreaders who choose this propagation strategy. The relevant parameters are detailed in table 3. As depicted by the black solid line in figure 5, when the cost ${C}_{w}$ is low, the proportion of spreaders choosing the text information base propagation strategy gradually increases over time. As the propagation cost ${C}_{w}$ increases, the proportion of spreaders favoring the text information base propagation strategy decreases accordingly but still experiences an upward trend, as indicated by the red solid line in figure 5. With further increases in cost, the proportion of spreaders who choose the text information propagation strategy becomes smaller and eventually diminishes to zero, as demonstrated by the blue solid line and the green solid line in figure 5. It is noteworthy that the difference between the green solid line and the blue solid line is marginal, indicating that when the cost becomes sufficiently high, the choice of strategy by spreaders becomes insensitive to cost variations.
Figure 5. The densities evolution of spreaders with different ${C}_{w}.$
Table 3. Parameter for text spreaders.
Symbol
Value
Symbol
Value
${\rm{\Lambda }}$
0.2
$b$
0.2
$\lambda $
0.19
$\varepsilon $
0.2
${\beta }_{1}$
0.45
${C}_{w}$
5,10,15,20
${\beta }_{2}$
0.2
${C}_{v}$
20
${\beta }_{3}$
0.55
$p$
0.4
${\alpha }_{1}$
0.15
$\alpha $
0.2
${\tau }_{1}$
5
$\tau $
10
${\tau }_{2}$
10
$N$
1000
Figure 6 simulates the impact of the cost ${C}_{v}$ for uploading rumors in video form on the proportion $y$ of spreaders who choose this propagation strategy. The relevant parameter settings are provided in table 4. Similar to figure 5, in general, the magnitude of the proportion $y$ of spreaders choosing the video information base propagation strategy is inversely proportional to the magnitude of the cost paid ${C}_{v}.$ However, unlike the trend depicted in figure 5, when ${C}_{v}=10,$ the proportion $y$ of spreaders who choose the video information base propagation strategy decreases over time. This phenomenon indicates that the proportion $y$ of spreaders choosing video information base propagation strategy is more sensitive to the change in the cost ${C}_{v}$ during this period. Notably, there is minimal distinction between the solid blue line and the solid green line, suggesting that $y$ becomes less sensitive to cost fluctuations as the cost attains a sufficiently high level.
Figure 6. The density evolution of spreaders with different ${C}_{v}.$
Table 4. Parameter for rumor spreaders.
Symbol
Value
Symbol
Value
${\rm{\Lambda }}$
0.2
$b$
0.2
$\lambda $
0.19
$\varepsilon $
0.2
${\beta }_{1}$
0.45
${C}_{w}$
10
${\beta }_{2}$
0.2
${C}_{v}$
5,10,15,20
${\beta }_{3}$
0.55
$p$
0.4
${\alpha }_{1}$
0.15
$\alpha $
0.2
${\tau }_{1}$
5
$\tau $
10
${\tau }_{2}$
10
$N$
1000
By comparing figure 5 with figure 6, we find that when the cost of the strategies are both ten, the proportion of spreaders choosing the strategy of text information base channel $x$ still continues to increase, while the proportion of spreaders choosing the strategy of video information base channel $y$ decreases to zero, which indicates that the spreaders are more sensitive to ${C}_{v}.$ Therefore, in formulating strategies to deal with rumor propagation, the management department needs to pay more attention to the management and monitoring of the text database channel, and formulate corresponding policies for ${C}_{v},$ so as to achieve better control effects with smaller control costs, and thus achieve more accurate rumor management. This kind of management strategy is expected to play a positive role in the actual response to rumor propagation.
Figure 7 simulates the time-evolution plot of the proportion of the spreaders who choose the video message bank to spread rumors at time delays ${\tau }_{2}=1{\rm{h}},3{\rm{h}},5{\rm{h}}.$ The relevant parameters are set as shown in table 5. As can be seen in figure 7, time delay ${\tau }_{2}$ is negatively correlated with the proportion $y$ of spreaders posting video rumors. When ${\tau }_{2}=1{\rm{h}},$ the proportion $y$ exhibits an increasing trend over time. However, as ${\tau }_{2}$ increases to 3h, $y$ shows a trend of initially rising and subsequently declining with time until it becomes 0. When ${\tau }_{2}$ further increases to 5h, $y$ steadily decreases with time. This indicates that the longer it takes for spreaders to produce videos, the smaller the proportion of spreaders choosing the information base propagation strategy. Therefore, in the real rumor propagation process, officials can implement stricter video posting requirements to extend the time delay in video rumor production. This strategic approach can effectively reduce the scale of rumor propagation and mitigate the negative impact of rumors.
Figure 7. The density evolution of video spreaders with different ${\tau }_{2}.$
Table 5. Parameter for video spreaders.
Symbol
Value
Symbol
Value
${\rm{\Lambda }}$
0.2
$b$
0.2
$\lambda $
0.19
$\varepsilon $
0.2
${\beta }_{1}$
0.45
${C}_{w}$
10
${\beta }_{2}$
0.2
${C}_{v}$
20
${\beta }_{3}$
0.55
$p$
0.4
${\alpha }_{1}$
0.15
$\alpha $
0.2
${\tau }_{1}$
5
$\tau $
10
${\tau }_{2}$
1,3,5
$N$
1000
In addition to analyzing the impact of the above factors on rumor propagation, the basic regeneration number ${R}_{0}$ is a very important indicator in the rumor propagation process. It can measure the rumor propagation ability. The larger the value of ${R}_{0},$ the stronger the rumor propagation ability, i.e., the more difficult the rumor is to be controlled. Therefore, it is very important to study the factors influencing the value of ${R}_{0}.$ In this subsection, we simulate the effects of removal rate $\lambda ,$ propagation rate ${\beta }_{2},$ and recovery rate ${\alpha }_{1}$ on the value of ${R}_{0}.$
The effects of parameters $\lambda ,$${\beta }_{2}$ and ${\alpha }_{1}$ on ${R}_{0}$ are simulated in figure 8, respectively. In figure 8(a), we can see that the basic regeneration number ${R}_{0}$ and the removal rate $\lambda $ are negatively correlated, i.e., ${R}_{0}$ decreases with the increase of the removal rate $\lambda .$ This observation implies that a higher removal rate weakens the rumor's propagation ability, and when the removal rate is sufficiently high, ${R}_{0}$ diminishes to zero. Figure 8(b) reveals that as the propagation rate ${\beta }_{2}$ increases, ${R}_{0}$ also increases. This trend indicates that a higher propagation rate enhances the rumor's propagation potential, leading to increased difficulty in controlling it. Finally, figure 8(c) demonstrates a negative correlation between ${R}_{0}$ and the recovery rate ${\alpha }_{1}.$ As the recovery rate ${\alpha }_{1}$ increases, the basic regeneration number ${R}_{0}$ decreases, indicating that the faster the rate at which people forget or lose interest in the rumor, the weaker the rumor propagation ability.
Figure 8. Parameter for $\lambda ,$${\beta }_{2}$ and ${\alpha }_{1}$ for ${R}_{0}.$
Figure 9 simulates the relation among the basic regeneration number ${R}_{0},$${\alpha }_{1}$ and ${\beta }_{2}.$ The relevant parameters are set as shown in table 6. From figure 9, we observe two noteworthy aspects. Firstly, as the propagation rate ${\beta }_{2}$ increases, the basic regeneration number ${R}_{0}$ also increases, which is consistent with the trend in figure 8(b). However, the extent to which changes in ${\beta }_{2}$ affect ${R}_{0}$ varies with the value of ${\alpha }_{1}.$ Specifically, for larger values of ${\alpha }_{1},$ changes in ${\beta }_{2}$ have a relatively minor impact on ${R}_{0}.$ Conversely, for smaller values of ${\alpha }_{1},$${R}_{0}$ becomes more sensitive to variations in ${\beta }_{2},$ with even slight changes in ${\beta }_{2}$, resulting in substantial fluctuations in ${R}_{0}.$ Secondly, the basic regeneration number ${R}_{0}$ is negatively correlated with the recovery rate ${\alpha }_{1},$ aligning with figure 8(c). Similarly, the influence of changes in ${\alpha }_{1}$ on ${R}_{0}$ is determined by the specific value of ${\beta }_{2}.$ When ${\beta }_{2}$ is small, alterations in ${\alpha }_{1}$ have a relatively modest effect on ${R}_{0}.$ Conversely, when ${\beta }_{2}$ is larger, ${R}_{0}$ becomes more sensitive to the changes in ${\alpha }_{1}.$
Figure 9. The relation among ${\beta }_{2},$${\alpha }_{1}$ and ${R}_{0}.$
Table 6. Parameter for the basic reproduction number.
Symbol
Value
Symbol
Value
${\rm{\Lambda }}$
0.2
$b$
0.2
$\lambda $
0.19
$\varepsilon $
0.2
${\beta }_{1}$
0.45
${C}_{w}$
10
${\beta }_{2}$
[0–1]
${C}_{v}$
20
${\beta }_{3}$
0.55
$p$
0.4
${\alpha }_{1}$
[0–1]
$\alpha $
0.2
${\tau }_{1}$
5
$\tau $
10
${\tau }_{2}$
10
$N$
1000
Figure 10 simulates the relation among the basic regeneration number ${R}_{0},$$\lambda $ and ${\beta }_{2}.$ The relevant parameter settings are shown in table 7. As depicted in figure 10, ${R}_{0}$ is negatively correlated with $\lambda ,$ which is in line with the results in figure 8(a). Notably, ${\beta }_{2}$ has a relatively small effect on this correlation trend. It's worth emphasizing that when $\lambda $ exceeds 0.5, changes in ${\beta }_{2}$ have little impact on ${R}_{0}.$ This underscores the significance of the removal rate $\lambda $ as a critical system parameter. When $\lambda $ reaches a sufficiently high value, regardless of how the propagation rate fluctuates, the basic reproduction number ${R}_{0}$ remains at zero. This implies that rumors cannot propagate on a large scale. Consequently, this finding suggests that enhancing the removal rate through measures such as blocking, deletion, and bans can be an effective strategy for controlling the widespread propagation of rumors.
Figure 10. The relation among ${\beta }_{2},$$\lambda $ and ${R}_{0}.$
Table 7. Parameter for the basic reproduction number.
Symbol
Value
Symbol
Value
${\rm{\Lambda }}$
0.2
$b$
0.2
$\lambda $
[0–1]
$\varepsilon $
0.2
${\beta }_{1}$
0.45
${C}_{w}$
10
${\beta }_{2}$
[0–1]
${C}_{v}$
5,10,15,20
${\beta }_{3}$
0.55
$p$
0.4
${\alpha }_{1}$
0.15
$\alpha $
0.2
${\tau }_{1}$
5
$\tau $
10
${\tau }_{2}$
10
$N$
1000
In figures 9 and 10, the $Z$-axis both denote ${R}_{0},$ the $X$-axis both denote ${\beta }_{2},$ while the $Y$-axis denote ${\alpha }_{1}$ and $\lambda ,$ respectively. comparing the $Y$-axis of the two figures, it can be seen that the rate of change of the surface along the $\lambda $-direction is greater in figure 9, which suggests that $\lambda $ has a more significant effect on ${R}_{0}.$ In other words, it is more efficient to increase the removal rate in controlling rumor propagation. This suggests that the relevant departments should focus on strengthening the management and control of information sources when formulating countermeasures. By means of gagging and other means, it is more likely to achieve significant results, effectively curbing the rise of ${R}_{0}$ and thus controlling the spread of rumors more efficiently.
5. Model application with a real dataset
In this section, we use a real dataset to evaluate the effectiveness of the model in this paper. The data is sourced from real Twitter datasets [43], which encompass information on 12 distinct rumors, spanning from the inception of each rumor to its cessation, encompassing both original tweets and retweeted content. From this set of 12 rumors, we identified the dataset with the most extensive volume of data, which is referred to as dataset 12 in this paper.
The dataset documents that the propagation dynamics of the rumor titled ‘A screenshot from MyLife.com confirms that mail bomb suspect Cesar Sayoc was registered as a Democrat'. As shown in table 8, each column within the dataset contains specific information related to individual tweets and retweets. This information includes user IDs, timestamps corresponding to the date and time of each tweet or retweet, tweet statuses, and other pertinent details. Tweets marked with the status ‘r' are categorized as rumor tweets, with the corresponding user IDs serving as the spreaders in the model proposed in this paper.
Table 8. Dataset 12 from the Twitter real datasets.
ID
Date & Time
···
Followers
State of Tweet
20414250
[‘2018', ‘Oct', ‘29', ‘20:03:27']
···
382
r
930195128
[‘2018', ‘Oct', ‘29', ‘20:03:10']
···
5457
r
45090008
[‘2018', ‘Oct', ‘29', ‘20:00:11']
···
96
a
1048362827201880000
[‘2018', ‘Oct', ‘29', ‘19:59:46']
···
229
r
819942782903009000
[‘2018', ‘Oct', ‘29', ‘19:59:13']
···
26
r
···
···
···
···
···
822430183261110000
[‘2018', ‘Oct', ‘29', ‘19:51:28']
···
1185
r
894929166
[‘2018', ‘Oct', ‘29', ‘19:47:58']
···
33
r
Subsequently, we performed data preprocessing on the 32,083 pieces of data from 0–76 h, eliminating data segments such as missing IDs, timestamp anomalies, etc., and finally obtained 14,931 cleaned data. Based on this cleaned data, we choose the whole data with state r as the dataset for the neural network algorithm. Specifically, we use the neural network algorithm on the TensorFlow platform to process the data from 0 to 76 h, taking the data from 0–36 h as the training set, and the data from 37–76 h as the validation set. A set of more desirable parameters is finally obtained, as shown in table 9. With this set of parameters, we can better fit the dynamic characteristics of actual rumor spreading.
Table 9. Parameter for the model validation.
Symbol
Value
Symbol
Value
${\rm{\Lambda }}$
0.19
$b$
0.001
$\lambda $
0.15
$\varepsilon $
0.2
${\beta }_{1}$
0.33
${C}_{w}$
10
${\beta }_{2}$
0.32
${C}_{v}$
20
${\beta }_{3}$
0.47
$p$
3.9
${\alpha }_{1}$
0.25
$\alpha $
0.99
${\tau }_{1}$
3
$\tau $
10
${\tau }_{2}$
10
$N$
1000
Figure 11(a) shows the fitting effect between the first 36 h actual data and the model, and it can be seen that the model can fit the trajectory of the actual data well. Subsequently, the parameters listed in table 9 were employed to forecast the rumor's progression within the framework of this paper's model. The prediction results are depicted as dotted lines in figure 11(b). Finally, we employed the last 40 h of data from the authentic dataset to validate the predictive accuracy of the model, as illustrated in figure 11(c). The results affirm the model's robust performance in anticipating rumor propagation dynamics, effectively emulating real-world propagation processes. This not only proves the feasibility and accuracy of the model, but also provides a powerful tool for us to gain a deeper understanding of the mechanism of rumor propagation.
Figure 11. The spreader density curve of the model and actual data curve.
Leveraging these findings, we can employ the model for rumor detection, early warning, and timely response, enabling us to proactively manage and mitigate the spread and impact of rumors. This represents a substantial step toward fostering a more harmonious online environment and holds significant practical application value.
Furthermore, we conducted a comparative analysis between the prediction results generated by the model presented in this paper and the classical $ISR$ model, as illustrated in figure 12. The comparative examination reveals that both the peak spreader density and the final spread size in the $ISRWVxy$ propagation model surpasses those in the traditional $ISR$ model. This discrepancy indicates that rumors propagate more extensively in the context of multi-channel propagation. Moreover, it's notable that the $ISRWVxy$ model attains its peak propagation earlier than the traditional $ISR$ model, indicating a faster rumor propagation rate in the multi-channel framework. Then, we use Python to evaluate the fitting results of the two models with real data respectively, and the evaluation results are shown in table 10. R-squared, RMSE (Root Mean Squared Error) and MAE (Mean Absolute Error) are used as evaluation indexes in the comparison experiment. A higher R-squared value indicates a better model fit, while a lower RMSE signifies closer alignment between predicted and actual values. Additionally, a smaller MAE value indicates improved prediction accuracy. From the experimental outcomes detailed in table 10, it is evident that the $ISRWVxy$ model outperforms the $ISR$ model. The $ISR$ model, which only takes into account the individual interactive communication, exhibits substantial errors when simulating real-world scenarios. In contrast, the multi-channel rumor propagation model, which incorporates information base propagation, more accurately mirrors the dynamics of rumor propagation. As a result, the model introduced in this paper holds the potential to offer valuable guidance for real-world rumor control efforts.
Figure 12. Comparison of $ISRWVxy,$$ISR$ and the actual data.
Table 10. Evaluation index.
Model
R-squared
RMSE
MAE
$ISRWVxy$
0.9365
0.0158
0.0113
$ISR$
−0.1449
0.0667
0.0590
6. Conclusion
In this paper, a multi-channel rumor propagation model including propagation of individuals game strategy and time delay was proposed. Firstly, the basic regeneration number was derived using the next generation matrix method, and six boundary equilibria and one internal equilibria of the system were obtained. Secondly, the local asymptotic stability of the seven equilibrium points was proved by using Routh–Hurwitz judgment, and Descartes' Rule of Signs. Subsequently, the above theoretical results were verified by numerical simulations. The results indicated that as the cost of propagation increases, the likelihood that a spreader chooses an online propagation strategy during the game decreases. This trend is more evident in the video information base channel strategy. This insight suggests that regulatory authorities can effectively curb rumor spreading by increasing the associated propagation costs. Furthermore, we analyzed the sensitivity of the threshold ${R}_{0}$ and found that the thresholds increase as the propagation rate rises. Meanwhile, the effect of the removal rate on the threshold is more obvious, and the regulatory authority can control the rumor more precisely by blocking and banning. Finally, we validated the model's effectiveness through the utilization of a real Twitter dataset. Moreover, experimental comparison with the classical $ISR$ model conclusively demonstrated the superiority of the proposed $ISRWVxy$ model in terms of performance and accuracy.
In summary, the multi-channel rumor propagation model, along with the theoretical analysis, numerical simulation and real data validation, provides some useful insights for rumor control and mitigation efforts. By considering factors such as propagation costs, time delay, propagation rate and removal rate that affect rumor propagation, the model in this paper helps to facilitate a more informed and prepared response to rumor propagation in contemporary society.
Competing interests
The authors declare that they have no competing interests.
This work was partially supported by the Project for the National Natural Science Foundation of China (72174121, 71774111), and the Program for Professor of Special Appointment (Eastern Scholar) at Shanghai Institutions of Higher Learning, and the Project for the Natural Science Foundation of Shanghai (21ZR1444100).
XiangT,LiQ,LiW,XiaoY2023 A rumor heat prediction model based on rumor and anti-rumor multiple messages and knowledge representation Inf. Process. Manage.60 103337
WangC,LiuR,WangY2023 The spread dynamics model of the interaction between rumors and derivative rumors in emergencies under the control strategy Chaos, Solitons Fractals175 114062 114062
LiJ,JiangH,MeiX,HuC,ZhangG2020 Dynamical analysis of rumor spreading model in multi-lingual environment and heterogeneous complex networks Inf. Sci.536 391 408
YinF,JiangX,QianX,XiaX,PanY,WuJ2022 Modeling and quantifying the influence of rumor and counter-rumor on information propagation dynamics Chaos, Solitons Fractals162 112392
ZhuL,LiuW-S,ZhangZ2020 Delay differential equations modeling of rumor propagation in both homogeneous and heterogeneous networks with a forced silence function Appl. Math. Comput.370 124925 124925
HuoL,ChenX,ZhaoL2023 The optimal event-triggered impulsive control of a stochastic rumor spreading model incorporating time delay using the particle swarm optimization algorithm J. Franklin Inst.360 4695 4718
LiM,ZhangH,GeorgescuP,LiT2021 The stochastic evolution of a rumor spreading model with two distinct spread inhibiting and attitude adjusting mechanisms in a homogeneous social network Physica A562 125321
JainA,DharJ,GuptaV2019 Stochastic model of rumor propagation dynamics on homogeneous social network with expert interaction and fluctuations in contact transmissions Physica A519 227 236
WangZ,XiaC,ChenZ,ChenG2020 Epidemic Propagation With Positive and Negative Preventive Information in Multiplex Networks IEEE Transactions on Cybernetics51 1454 1462
WangJ,JiangH,MaT,HuC2019 Global dynamics of the multi-lingual SIR rumor spreading model with cross-transmitted mechanism Chaos, Solitons Fractals126 148 157
SongZ,XuJ,ZhenB2019 Mixed-coexistence of periodic orbits and chaotic attractors in an inertial neural system with a nonmonotonic activation function Mathematical Biosciences and Engineering16 6406 6425
ChengY,HuoL,ZhaoL2021 Dynamical behaviors and control measures of rumor-spreading model in consideration of the infected media and time delay Inf. Sci.564 237 253
DongY,HuoL,ZhaoL2022 An improved two-layer model for rumor propagation considering time delay and event-triggered impulsive control strategy Chaos, Solitons Fractals164 112711
AskarizadehM,Tork LadaniB,ManshaeiM H2019 An evolutionary game model for analysis of rumor propagation and control in social networks Physica A523 21 39
LiQ,XiangT,DaiT,XiaoY2023 An information dissemination model based on the Rumor & Anti-Rumor & stimulate-rumor and tripartite cognitive game IEEE Transactions on Cognitive and Developmental Systems15 925 937
MeiJ,WangS,XiaD,HuJ2022 Global stability and optimal control analysis of a knowledge transmission model in multilayer networks Chaos, Solitons Fractals164 112708 112708
DongY,HuoL,XieX,LiM2023 An improved ISR-WV rumor propagation model based on multichannels with time delay and pulse vaccination Chin. Phys.32 70205 70205
FuF,RosenbloomD I,WangL,NowakM A2011 Imitation dynamics of vaccination behaviour on social networks Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences278 42 49